Philosophic inquiry led to all the sciences on earth. It all came from asking rational questions and just not accepting all the fairy tales or old wives tales told to them growing up.
My parents were very religious people. However, I was always a very spiritual person because I had actually met the Archangels who came to save me at 2 from Whooping cough.
So, to me, God and Angels were not ever theoretical because I met them as a child. Once you have an experience like this you might listen to people that tell you something else but you are also going to be laughing at these people behind your back (or you are going to feel really sorry for them when they kill themselves because they never met God or Angels like you did).
So, being spiritual and talking and having conversations with Jesus and Archangel Michael and Saint Germain and other Ascended Masters or Angels or with God was pretty normal for me growing up.
I didn't always like what they told me but I also found out the hard way that they were always right about everything and I was just too immature sometimes to get the real truths behind what they were telling me.
So, by the time I was 15 I started listening more so I wouldn't die like I almost did from whooping cough and then a concussion and night time seizures from rock climbing (without a helmet) in those days ( 1950s and 1960s and 1970s) mostly.
So, philosophical inquiry led to all the sciences including Psychology and Anthropology.
It's sort of like when a 4 year old asks: "Daddy. why is the sky blue?"
If you don't know for sure you can make something up like Daddies did for thousands of years. However, if you are scientific about all this the sky is blue because of our atmosphere the sunlight refracts and here on earth because of the balance of gases in our atmosphere like Oxygen, and Nitrogen it refracts the sky into mostly a blue range.
This is the actual scientific Truth of why our sky is blue. Not something someone made up because they didn't want to look stupid in front of their 4 year old kid.
So, when you can use philosophical inquiry regarding EVERYTHING in your life you start to make decisions in your life that actually might physically and psychologically keep you alive past 30 years of age.
If you wondered why people don't die mostly before 60 like they did in 1900 it's mostly because people got more reasonable and started asking real questions and getting real scientific answers instead of just fairy tales father and mothers made up so they didn't look stupid in front of their children for thousands of years.
So, Philosophy specifically starting at Palomar College around 1971 was when I started to ask the kind of questions that finally led me to understand my predicament as a human being here on earth in a way that actually made sense to a logical rational reasonable person like myself.
So, basically what I learned in college kept me alive past age 25 which is when I thought I would have checked out before.
So, by the Grace of God I'm still alive because I went to college and studied Philosophy, Psychology and Anthropology starting around 1971.
I think my middle Aged Crisis started when my father died when I was 37 in 1985. I went to India and Nepal and Thailand and Japan for 4 months with my family to try to move on from my father's passing. However, looking back now I realize leaving my mother alone and leaving her with us going to Asia for 4 months likely didn't help her any either. However, I was struggling to make sense of my life because I had always been very YOUTH CULTURE oriented like Surfing, Skiing, Mountain Climbing, OFF road motorcycles but also I was married since I was 26 years old when my first child was born too.
I was completely unprepared for my father's passing and didn't really understand how important my father was to my own psychological survival either. So, about 9 years after my father passed on my wife and I divorced partly because I wasn't really okay after my father passed on. Then I fell rock climbing after tearing my muscles of the back of my right leg and almost drowned in Cold Water near Big Sur. Then I tore my left Hamstring and had to drag my left leg for 6 months because I couldn't afford to get either injury properly fixed because I had teenagers to raise and get into college. Need I go on?
So, the middle Aged Crazy episode ended when I almost died for 9 months myself. I had to quickly get over my youth culture approach to everything and I became Grateful for every moment I had left with my family and friends and stopped worrying about getting old and dying.
After all, We ALL are going to die. It's just a matter of when. So, if you can just enjoy and be grateful for each moment you have left you are basically prepared for death every moment of your life.
I was just thinking about all the people having presently a midlife crisis because of Trump trashing their business or stock portfolio right now worldwide OR CAUSING THEM TO GET FIRED FROM THEIR JOBS IN VARIOUS WAYS.
This is a really awful time for many people that they might not survive. However, here's the thing!
NECESSITY IS THE MOTHER OF INVENTION
SO, WITH GOD'S HELP EVERYONE THAT CAN WILL FIND A WAY TO SURVIVE ALL THIS!
By God's Grace
Begin partial quote from:https://www.google.com/search?client=firefox-b-1-d&q=middle+aged+crazy
What is an example of middle age crisis?
Some common causes of midlife crises include personal life changes such as divorce, the death of a loved one, or an illness. Other causes of a midlife crisis include, but are not limited to: Aging.
And Just like Trump President Herbert Hoover was also a fan of Tariffs which is what started the last Great Depression when all of this really got out of hand. Then Japan was forbidden by the U.S. to buy U.S. Oil which caused them to attack Pearl Harbor as a point of Samurai Honor of the warrior class in Japan.
People when I grew up in the 1950s and 1960s were still having PTSD experiences from what they experienced during the Great Depression COMBINED with World War II which was basically caused by Tariffs to begin with eventually. Because that is where the war actually started from punishing Germany because of World War I led to Hitler taking over much like Trump is doing now.
Begin quote from:https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Great_Depression
The Great Depression was a severe global economic downturn from 1929 to 1939. The period was characterized by high rates of unemployment and poverty,
drastic reductions in industrial production and international trade,
and widespread bank and business failures around the world. The economic contagion began in 1929 in the United States, the largest economy in the world, with the devastating Wall Street stock market crash of October 1929 often considered the beginning of the Depression. Among the countries with the most unemployed were the U.S., the United Kingdom, and Germany.
The Depression was preceded by a period of industrial growth and social development known as the "Roaring Twenties". Much of the profit generated by the boom was invested in speculation, such as on the stock market, contributing to growing wealth inequality. Banks were subject to minimal regulation,
resulting in loose lending and widespread debt. By 1929, declining
spending had led to reductions in manufacturing output and rising
unemployment. Share values continued to rise until the October 1929
crash, after which the slide continued until July 1932, accompanied by a
loss of confidence in the financial system. By 1933, the U.S.
unemployment rate had risen to 25%, about one-third of farmers had lost
their land, and 9,000 of its 25,000 banks had gone out of business.
President Herbert Hoover was unwilling to intervene heavily in the economy, and in 1930 he signed the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act, which worsened the Depression. In the 1932 presidential election, Hoover was defeated by Franklin D. Roosevelt, who from 1933 pursued a set of expansive New Deal
programs in order to provide relief and create jobs. In Germany, which
depended heavily on U.S. loans, the crisis caused unemployment to rise
to nearly 30% and fueled political extremism, paving the way for Adolf Hitler's Nazi Party to rise to power in 1933.
Between 1929 and 1932, worldwide gross domestic product (GDP) fell by an estimated 15%; in the U.S., the Depression resulted in a 30% contraction in GDP.[1]
Recovery varied greatly around the world. Some economies, such as the
U.S., Germany and Japan started to recover by the mid-1930s; others,
like France, did not return to pre-shock growth rates until later in the
decade.[2] The Depression had devastating economic effects on both wealthy and poor countries: all experienced drops in personal income, prices (deflation), tax revenues, and profits. International trade fell by more than 50%, and unemployment in some countries rose as high as 33%.[3]Cities around the world, especially those dependent on heavy industry,
were heavily affected. Construction virtually halted in many countries,
and farming communities and rural areas suffered as crop prices fell by
up to 60%.[4][5][6] Faced with plummeting demand and few job alternatives, areas dependent on primary sector industries suffered the most.[7] The outbreak of World War II
in 1939 ended the Depression, as it stimulated factory production,
providing jobs for women as militaries absorbed large numbers of young,
unemployed men.
The precise causes for the Great Depression are disputed. One set
of historians, for example, focuses on non-monetary economic causes.
Among these, some regard the Wall Street crash itself as the main cause;
others consider that the crash was a mere symptom of more general
economic trends of the time, which had already been underway in the late
1920s.[3][8] A contrasting set of views, which rose to prominence in the later part of the 20th century,[9] ascribes a more prominent role to failures of monetary policy.
According to those authors, while general economic trends can explain
the emergence of the downturn, they fail to account for its severity and
longevity; they argue that these were caused by the lack of an adequate
response to the crises of liquidity that followed the initial economic
shock of 1929 and the subsequent bank failures accompanied by a general
collapse of the financial markets.[1]
Overview
The unemployment rate in the U.S. during 1910–60, with the years of the Great Depression (1929–39) highlighted
The economic picture at the beginning of the crisis
After the Wall Street crash of 1929, when the Dow Jones Industrial Average
dropped from 381 to 198 over the course of two months, optimism
persisted for some time. The stock market rose in early 1930, with the
Dow returning to 294 (pre-depression levels) in April 1930, before
steadily declining for years, to a low of 41 in 1932.[10]
At the beginning, governments and businesses spent more in the
first half of 1930 than in the corresponding period of the previous
year. On the other hand, consumers, many of whom suffered severe losses
in the stock market the previous year, cut expenditures by 10%. In
addition, beginning in the mid-1930s, a severe drought ravaged the agricultural heartland of the U.S.[11]
Interest rates dropped to low levels by mid-1930, but expected deflation and the continuing reluctance of people to borrow meant that consumer spending and investment remained low.[12]
By May 1930, automobile sales declined to below the levels of 1928.
Prices, in general, began to decline, although wages held steady in
1930. Then a deflationary spiral
started in 1931. Farmers faced a worse outlook; declining crop prices
and a Great Plains drought crippled their economic outlook. At its peak,
the Great Depression saw nearly 10% of all Great Plains farms change
hands despite federal assistance.[13]
Beyond the United States
At first, the decline in the U.S. economy
was the factor that triggered economic downturns in most other
countries due to a decline in trade, capital movement, and global
business confidence. Then, internal weaknesses or strengths in each
country made conditions worse or better. For example, the U.K. economy,
which experienced an economic downturn throughout most of the late
1920s, was less severely impacted by the shock of the depression than
the U.S. By contrast, the German economy saw a similar decline in
industrial output as that observed in the U.S.[14]
Some economic historians attribute the differences in the rates of
recovery and relative severity of the economic decline to whether
particular countries had been able to effectively devaluate their
currencies or not. This is supported by the contrast in how the crisis
progressed in, e.g., Britain, Argentina and Brazil, all of which
devalued their currencies early and returned to normal patterns of
growth relatively rapidly and countries which stuck to the gold standard, such as France or Belgium.[15]
Frantic attempts by individual countries to shore up their economies through protectionist policies – such as the 1930 U.S. Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act and retaliatory tariffs in other countries – exacerbated the collapse in global trade, contributing to the depression.[16] By 1933, the economic decline pushed world trade to one third of its level compared to four years earlier.[17]
Crowd gathering at the intersection of Wall Street and Broad Street after the 1929 crash
Origins
While the precise causes for the occurrence of the Great Depression
are disputed and can be traced to both global and national phenomena,
its immediate origins are most conveniently examined in the context of
the U.S. economy, from which the initial crisis spread to the rest of
the world.[19]
In the aftermath of World War I, the Roaring Twenties brought considerable wealth to the United States and Western Europe.[20]
Initially, the year 1929 dawned with good economic prospects: despite a
minor crash on 25 March 1929, the market seemed to gradually improve
through September. Stock prices began to slump in September, and were
volatile at the end of the month.[21] A large sell-off of stocks began in mid-October. Finally, on 24 October, Black Thursday,
the American stock market crashed 11% at the opening bell. Actions to
stabilize the market failed, and on 28 October, Black Monday, the market
crashed another 12%. The panic peaked the next day on Black Tuesday,
when the market saw another 11% drop.[22][23]
Thousands of investors were ruined, and billions of dollars had been lost; many stocks could not be sold at any price.[23]
The market recovered 12% on Wednesday but by then significant damage
had been done. Though the market entered a period of recovery from 14
November until 17 April 1930, the general situation had been a prolonged
slump. From September 1929 to 8 July 1932, the market lost 85% of its
value.[24]
Despite the crash, the worst of the crisis did not reverberate around
the world until after 1929. The crisis hit panic levels again in
December 1930, with a bank run on the Bank of United States, a former privately run bank, bearing no relation to the U.S. government (not to be confused with the Federal Reserve). Unable to pay out to all of its creditors, the bank failed.[25][26]
Among the 608 American banks that closed in November and December 1930,
the Bank of United States accounted for a third of the total
$550 million deposits lost and, with its closure, bank failures reached a
critical mass.[27]
The Smoot–Hawley Act and the Breakdown of International Trade
Willis C. Hawley (left) and Reed Smoot in April 1929, shortly before the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act passed the House of Representatives
In an initial response to the crisis, the U.S. Congress passed the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act
on 17 June 1930. The Act was ostensibly aimed at protecting the
American economy from foreign competition by imposing high tariffs on
foreign imports. The consensus view among economists and economic historians (including Keynesians, Monetarists and Austrian economists)
is that the passage of the Smoot–Hawley Tariff had, in fact, achieved
an opposite effect to what was intended. It exacerbated the Great
Depression[28]
by preventing economic recovery after domestic production recovered,
hampering the volume of trade; still there is disagreement as to the
precise extent of the Act's influence.
In the popular view, the Smoot–Hawley Tariff was one of the leading causes of the depression.[29][30] In a 1995 survey of American economic historians, two-thirds agreed that the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act at least worsened the Great Depression.[31] According to the U.S. Senate website, the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act is among the most catastrophic acts in congressional history.[32]
Many economists have argued that the sharp decline in
international trade after 1930 helped to worsen the depression,
especially for countries significantly dependent on foreign trade. Most
historians and economists blame the Act for worsening the depression by
seriously reducing international trade and causing retaliatory tariffs
in other countries. While foreign trade was a small part of overall
economic activity in the U.S. and was concentrated in a few businesses
like farming, it was a much larger factor in many other countries.[33] The average ad valorem
(value based) rate of duties on dutiable imports for 1921–1925 was
25.9% but under the new tariff it jumped to 50% during 1931–1935. In
dollar terms, American exports declined over the next four years from
about $5.2 billion in 1929 to $1.7 billion in 1933; so, not only did the
physical volume of exports fall, but also the prices fell by about 1⁄3 as written. Hardest hit were farm commodities such as wheat, cotton, tobacco, and lumber.[34]
Governments around the world took various steps into spending
less money on foreign goods such as: "imposing tariffs, import quotas,
and exchange controls". These restrictions triggered much tension among
countries that had large amounts of bilateral trade, causing major
export-import reductions during the depression. Not all governments
enforced the same measures of protectionism. Some countries raised
tariffs drastically and enforced severe restrictions on foreign exchange
transactions, while other countries reduced "trade and exchange
restrictions only marginally":[35]
"Countries that remained on the gold standard, keeping
currencies fixed, were more likely to restrict foreign trade." These
countries "resorted to protectionist policies to strengthen the balance of payments and limit gold losses." They hoped that these restrictions and depletions would hold the economic decline.[35]
Countries that abandoned the gold standard allowed their currencies to depreciate
which caused their balance of payments to strengthen. It also freed up
monetary policy so that central banks could lower interest rates and act
as lenders of last resort. They possessed the best policy instruments
to fight the Depression and did not need protectionism.[35]
"The length and depth of a country's economic downturn and the
timing and vigor of its recovery are related to how long it remained on
the gold standard.
Countries abandoning the gold standard relatively early experienced
relatively mild recessions and early recoveries. In contrast, countries
remaining on the gold standard experienced prolonged slumps."[35]
The gold standard and the spreading of global depression
The gold standard
was the primary transmission mechanism of the Great Depression. Even
countries that did not face bank failures and a monetary contraction
first-hand were forced to join the deflationary policy since higher
interest rates in countries that performed a deflationary policy led to a
gold outflow in countries with lower interest rates. Under the gold
standard's price–specie flow mechanism,
countries that lost gold but nevertheless wanted to maintain the gold
standard had to permit their money supply to decrease and the domestic
price level to decline (deflation).[36][37]
There is also consensus that protectionist policies, and primarily the passage of the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act, helped to exacerbate, or even cause the Great Depression.[31]
Some economic studies have indicated that the rigidities of the gold standard
not only spread the downturn worldwide, but also suspended gold
convertibility (devaluing the currency in gold terms) that did the most
to make recovery possible.[39]
Every major currency left the gold standard during the Great Depression. The UK was the first to do so. Facing speculative attacks on the pound and depleting gold reserves, in September 1931 the Bank of England
ceased exchanging pound notes for gold and the pound was floated on
foreign exchange markets. Japan and the Scandinavian countries followed
in 1931. Other countries, such as Italy and the United States, remained
on the gold standard into 1932 or 1933, while a few countries in the
so-called "gold bloc", led by France and including Poland, Belgium and
Switzerland, stayed on the standard until 1935–36.
According to later analysis, the earliness with which a country
left the gold standard reliably predicted its economic recovery. For
example, The UK and Scandinavia, which left the gold standard in 1931,
recovered much earlier than France and Belgium, which remained on gold
much longer. Countries such as China, which had a silver standard,
almost avoided the depression entirely. The connection between leaving
the gold standard as a strong predictor of that country's severity of
its depression and the length of time of its recovery has been shown to
be consistent for dozens of countries, including developing countries. This partly explains why the experience and length of the depression differed between regions and states around the world.[40]
German banking crisis of 1931 and British crisis
The financial crisis escalated out of control in mid-1931, starting with the collapse of the Credit Anstalt in Vienna in May.[41][42]
This put heavy pressure on Germany, which was already in political
turmoil. With the rise in violence of National Socialist ('Nazi') and
Communist movements, as well as investor nervousness at harsh government
financial policies,[43]
investors withdrew their short-term money from Germany as confidence
spiraled downward. The Reichsbank lost 150 million marks in the first
week of June, 540 million in the second, and 150 million in two days,
19–20 June. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover called
for a moratorium on payment of war reparations.
This angered Paris, which depended on a steady flow of German payments,
but it slowed the crisis down, and the moratorium was agreed to in July
1931. An International conference in London later in July produced no
agreements but on 19 August a standstill agreement froze Germany's
foreign liabilities for six months. Germany received emergency funding
from private banks in New York as well as the Bank of International
Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding only slowed the
process. Industrial failures began in Germany, a major bank closed in
July and a two-day holiday for all German banks was declared. Business
failures were more frequent in July, and spread to Romania and Hungary. The crisis continued to get worse in Germany, bringing political upheaval that finally led to the coming to power of Hitler's Nazi regime in January 1933.[44]
The world financial crisis now began to overwhelm Britain;
investors around the world started withdrawing their gold from London at
the rate of £2.5 million per day.[45]
Credits of £25 million each from the Bank of France and the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York and an issue of £15 million fiduciary note
slowed, but did not reverse, the British crisis. The financial crisis
now caused a major political crisis in Britain in August 1931. With
deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced budget; the divided
cabinet of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald's Labour government agreed;
it proposed to raise taxes, cut spending, and most controversially, to
cut unemployment benefits 20%. The attack on welfare was unacceptable to
the Labour movement. MacDonald wanted to resign, but King George V
insisted he remain and form an all-party coalition "National Government".
The Conservative and Liberals parties signed on, along with a small
cadre of Labour, but the vast majority of Labour leaders denounced
MacDonald as a traitor for leading the new government. Britain went off
the gold standard,
and suffered relatively less than other major countries in the Great
Depression. In the 1931 British election, the Labour Party was virtually
destroyed, leaving MacDonald as prime minister for a largely
Conservative coalition.[46][47]
Turning point and recovery
The
overall course of the Depression in the United States, as reflected in
per-capita GDP (average income per person) shown in constant year 2000
dollars, plus some of the key events of the period. Dotted red line =
long-term trend 1920–1970.[48]
In most countries of the world, recovery from the Great Depression began in 1933.[8] In the U.S., recovery began in early 1933,[8]
but the U.S. did not return to 1929 GNP for over a decade and still had
an unemployment rate of about 15% in 1940, albeit down from the high of
25% in 1933.
There is no consensus among economists regarding the motive force
for the U.S. economic expansion that continued through most of the Roosevelt years (and the 1937 recession that interrupted it). The common view among most economists is that Roosevelt's New Deal
policies either caused or accelerated the recovery, although his
policies were never aggressive enough to bring the economy completely
out of recession. Some economists have also called attention to the
positive effects from expectations of reflation and rising nominal interest rates that Roosevelt's words and actions portended.[49][50] It was the rollback of those same reflationary policies that led to the interruption of a recession beginning in late 1937.[51][52] One contributing policy that reversed reflation was the Banking Act of 1935, which effectively raised reserve requirements, causing a monetary contraction that helped to thwart the recovery.[53] GDP returned to its upward trend in 1938.[48] A revisionist view among some economists holds that the New Deal prolonged the Great Depression, as they argue that National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933 and National Labor Relations Act of 1935 restricted competition and established price fixing.[54]John Maynard Keynes
did not think that the New Deal under Roosevelt single-handedly ended
the Great Depression: "It is, it seems, politically impossible for a
capitalistic democracy to organize expenditure on the scale necessary to
make the grand experiments which would prove my case—except in war
conditions."[55]
According to Christina Romer,
the money supply growth caused by huge international gold inflows was a
crucial source of the recovery of the United States economy, and that
the economy showed little sign of self-correction. The gold inflows were
partly due to devaluation of the U.S. dollar and partly due to deterioration of the political situation in Europe.[56] In their book, A Monetary History of the United States, Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz also attributed the recovery to monetary factors, and contended that it was much slowed by poor management of money by the Federal Reserve System. Chairman of the Federal Reserve (2006–2014) Ben Bernanke agreed that monetary factors played important roles both in the worldwide economic decline and eventual recovery.[57]
Bernanke also saw a strong role for institutional factors, particularly
the rebuilding and restructuring of the financial system,[58] and pointed out that the Depression should be examined in an international perspective.[59]
Role of women and household economics
Women's primary role was as housewives; without a steady flow of
family income, their work became much harder in dealing with food and
clothing and medical care. Birthrates fell everywhere, as children were
postponed until families could financially support them. The average
birthrate for 14 major countries fell 12% from 19.3 births per thousand
population in 1930, to 17.0 in 1935.[60] In Canada, half of Roman Catholic women defied Church teachings and used contraception to postpone births.[61]
Among the few women in the labor force, layoffs were less common
in the white-collar jobs and they were typically found in light
manufacturing work. However, there was a widespread demand to limit
families to one paid job, so that wives might lose employment if their
husband was employed.[62][63][64] Across Britain, there was a tendency for married women to join the labor force, competing for part-time jobs especially.[65][66]
In France, very slow population growth, especially in comparison
to Germany continued to be a serious issue in the 1930s. Support for
increasing welfare programs during the depression included a focus on
women in the family. The Conseil Supérieur de la Natalité campaigned for
provisions enacted in the Code de la Famille (1939) that increased
state assistance to families with children and required employers to
protect the jobs of fathers, even if they were immigrants.[67]
In rural and small-town areas, women expanded their operation of
vegetable gardens to include as much food production as possible. In the
United States, agricultural organizations sponsored programs to teach
housewives how to optimize their gardens and to raise poultry for meat
and eggs.[68] Rural women made feed sack dresses and other items for themselves and their families and homes from feed sacks.[69]
In American cities, African American women quiltmakers enlarged their
activities, promoted collaboration, and trained neophytes. Quilts were
created for practical use from various inexpensive materials and
increased social interaction for women and promoted camaraderie and
personal fulfillment.[70]
Oral history provides evidence for how housewives in a modern
industrial city handled shortages of money and resources. Often they
updated strategies their mothers used when they were growing up in poor
families. Cheap foods were used, such as soups, beans and noodles. They
purchased the cheapest cuts of meat—sometimes even horse meat—and
recycled the Sunday roast
into sandwiches and soups. They sewed and patched clothing, traded with
their neighbors for outgrown items, and made do with colder homes. New
furniture and appliances were postponed until better days. Many women
also worked outside the home, or took boarders, did laundry for trade or
cash, and did sewing for neighbors in exchange for something they could
offer. Extended families used mutual aid—extra food, spare rooms,
repair-work, cash loans—to help cousins and in-laws.[71]
In Japan, official government policy was deflationary and the
opposite of Keynesian spending. Consequently, the government launched a
campaign across the country to induce households to reduce their
consumption, focusing attention on spending by housewives.[72]
In Germany, the government tried to reshape private household
consumption under the Four-Year Plan of 1936 to achieve German economic
self-sufficiency. The Nazi women's organizations, other propaganda
agencies and the authorities all attempted to shape such consumption as
economic self-sufficiency was needed to prepare for and to sustain the
coming war. The organizations, propaganda agencies and authorities
employed slogans that called up traditional values of thrift and healthy
living. However, these efforts were only partly successful in changing
the behavior of housewives.[73]
World War II and recovery
A female factory worker in 1942, Fort Worth, Texas. Women entered the workforce as men were drafted into the armed forces.
The common view among economic historians is that the Great Depression ended with the advent of World War II.
Many economists believe that government spending on the war caused or
at least accelerated recovery from the Great Depression, though some
consider that it did not play a very large role in the recovery, though
it did help in reducing unemployment.[8][74][75][76]
The rearmament policies leading up to World War II helped
stimulate the economies of Europe in 1937–1939. By 1937, unemployment in
Britain had fallen to 1.5 million. The mobilization of manpower following the outbreak of war in 1939 ended unemployment.[77]
The American mobilization for World War II at the end of 1941 moved approximately 10 million people out of the civilian labor force and into the war.[78]
This finally eliminated the last effects from the Great Depression and brought the U.S. unemployment rate down below 10%.[79]
World War II had a dramatic effect on many parts of the American economy.[80]
Government-financed capital spending accounted for only 5% of the
annual U.S. investment in industrial capital in 1940; by 1943, the
government accounted for 67% of U.S. capital investment.[80]
The massive war spending doubled economic growth rates, either masking
the effects of the Depression or essentially ending the Depression.
Businessmen ignored the mounting national debt and heavy new taxes, redoubling their efforts for greater output to take advantage of generous government contracts.[81]
During World War I many countries suspended their gold standard in varying ways. There was high inflation from WWI, and in the 1920s in the Weimar Republic, Austria,
and throughout Europe. In the late 1920s there was a scramble to
deflate prices to get the gold standard's conversation rates back on
track to pre-WWI levels, by causing deflation and high unemployment through monetary policy. In 1933 FDR signed Executive Order 6102 and in 1934 signed the Gold Reserve Act.[82]
The two classic competing economic theories of the Great Depression are the Keynesian (demand-driven) and the Monetarist explanation.[84] There are also various heterodox theories
that downplay or reject the explanations of the Keynesians and
monetarists. The consensus among demand-driven theories is that a
large-scale loss of confidence led to a sudden reduction in consumption
and investment spending. Once panic and deflation set in, many people
believed they could avoid further losses by keeping clear of the
markets. Holding money became profitable as prices dropped lower and a
given amount of money bought ever more goods, exacerbating the drop in
demand.[85] Monetarists believe that the Great Depression started as an ordinary recession, but the shrinking of the money supply greatly exacerbated the economic situation, causing a recession to descend into the Great Depression.[86]
Economists and economic historians are almost evenly split as to
whether the traditional monetary explanation that monetary forces were
the primary cause of the Great Depression is right, or the traditional
Keynesian explanation that a fall in autonomous spending, particularly
investment, is the primary explanation for the onset of the Great
Depression.[87] Today there is also significant academic support for the debt deflation theory and the expectations hypothesis that – building on the monetary explanation of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz – add non-monetary explanations.[88][89]
There is a consensus that the Federal Reserve System should have cut short the process of monetary deflation and banking collapse, by expanding the money supply and acting as lender of last resort. If they had done this, the economic downturn would have been far less severe and much shorter.[90]
Mainstream explanations
U.S. industrial production, 1928–1939
Modern mainstream economists see the reasons in
A money supply reduction (Monetarists) and therefore a banking crisis, reduction of credit, and bankruptcies.
Insufficient spending, the money supply reduction, and debt on margin led to falling prices and further bankruptcies (Irving Fisher's debt deflation).
Monetarist view
The Great Depression in the U.S. from a monetary view. Real gross domestic product in 1996-Dollar (blue), price index (red), money supply M2 (green) and number of banks (grey). All data adjusted to 1929 = 100%.Crowd at New York's American Union Bank during a bank run early in the Great Depression
The monetarist explanation was given by American economists Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz.[91]
They argued that the Great Depression was caused by the banking crisis
that caused one-third of all banks to vanish, a reduction of bank
shareholder wealth and more importantly monetary contraction of 35%, which they called "The Great Contraction". This caused a price drop of 33% (deflation).[92]
By not lowering interest rates, by not increasing the monetary base and
by not injecting liquidity into the banking system to prevent it from
crumbling, the Federal Reserve passively watched the transformation of a
normal recession into the Great Depression. Friedman and Schwartz
argued that the downward turn in the economy, starting with the stock
market crash, would merely have been an ordinary recession if the
Federal Reserve had taken aggressive action.[93][94] This view was endorsed in 2002 by Federal Reserve GovernorBen Bernanke in a speech honoring Friedman and Schwartz with this statement:
Let me end my talk by abusing
slightly my status as an official representative of the Federal Reserve.
I would like to say to Milton and Anna: Regarding the Great Depression,
you're right. We did it. We're very sorry. But thanks to you, we won't
do it again.
The Federal Reserve allowed some large public bank failures – particularly that of the New York Bank of United States
– which produced panic and widespread runs on local banks, and the
Federal Reserve sat idly by while banks collapsed. Friedman and Schwartz
argued that, if the Fed had provided emergency lending to these key
banks, or simply bought government bonds on the open market
to provide liquidity and increase the quantity of money after the key
banks fell, all the rest of the banks would not have fallen after the
large ones did, and the money supply would not have fallen as far and as
fast as it did.[97]
With significantly less money to go around, businesses could not
get new loans and could not even get their old loans renewed, forcing
many to stop investing. This interpretation blames the Federal Reserve
for inaction, especially the New York branch.[98]
One reason why the Federal Reserve did not act to limit the decline of the money supply was the gold standard. At that time, the amount of credit the Federal Reserve could issue was limited by the Federal Reserve Act,
which required 40% gold backing of Federal Reserve Notes issued. By the
late 1920s, the Federal Reserve had almost hit the limit of allowable
credit that could be backed by the gold in its possession. This credit
was in the form of Federal Reserve demand notes.[99]
A "promise of gold" is not as good as "gold in the hand", particularly
when they only had enough gold to cover 40% of the Federal Reserve Notes
outstanding. During the bank panics, a portion of those demand notes
was redeemed for Federal Reserve gold. Since the Federal Reserve had hit
its limit on allowable credit, any reduction in gold in its vaults had
to be accompanied by a greater reduction in credit. On 5 April 1933,
President Roosevelt signed Executive Order 6102 making the private ownership of gold certificates, coins and bullion illegal, reducing the pressure on Federal Reserve gold.[99]
Keynes's basic idea was simple: to keep people fully employed,
governments have to run deficits when the economy is slowing, as the
private sector would not invest enough to keep production at the normal
level and bring the economy out of recession. Keynesian economists
called on governments during times of economic crisis to pick up the slack by increasing government spending or cutting taxes.
As the Depression wore on, Franklin D. Roosevelt tried public works, farm subsidies,
and other devices to restart the U.S. economy, but never completely
gave up trying to balance the budget. According to the Keynesians, this
improved the economy, but Roosevelt never spent enough to bring the
economy out of recession until the start of World War II.[100]
Debt deflation
Irving Fisher
argued that the predominant factor leading to the Great Depression was a
vicious circle of deflation and growing over-indebtedness.[101]
He outlined nine factors interacting with one another under conditions
of debt and deflation to create the mechanics of boom to bust. The chain
of events proceeded as follows:
Debt liquidation and distress selling
Contraction of the money supply as bank loans are paid off
A fall in the level of asset prices
A still greater fall in the net worth of businesses, precipitating bankruptcies
A fall in nominal interest rates and a rise in deflation adjusted interest rates[101]
During the Crash of 1929 preceding the Great Depression, margin requirements were only 10%.[102] Brokerage firms, in other words, would lend $9 for every $1 an investor had deposited. When the market fell, brokers called in these loans, which could not be paid back.[103] Banks began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering multiple bank runs.
Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to
prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to
the loss of billions of dollars in assets.[103]
Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell
by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the
panic of 1929 and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 U.S. banks
failed. (In all, 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s.) By April 1933,
around $7 billion in deposits had been frozen in failed banks or those
left unlicensed after the March Bank Holiday.[104]
Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans that
borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits
looking poor, capital investment
and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans
and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more
conservative in their lending.[103] Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A vicious cycle developed and the downward spiral accelerated.
The liquidation of debt could not keep up with the fall of prices
that it caused. The mass effect of the stampede to liquidate increased
the value of each dollar owed, relative to the value of declining asset
holdings. The very effort of individuals to lessen their burden of debt
effectively increased it. Paradoxically, the more the debtors paid, the
more they owed.[101] This self-aggravating process turned a 1930 recession into a 1933 great depression.
Fisher's debt-deflation theory initially lacked mainstream
influence because of the counter-argument that debt-deflation
represented no more than a redistribution from one group (debtors) to
another (creditors). Pure re-distributions should have no significant
macroeconomic effects.
Building on both the monetary hypothesis of Milton Friedman and
Anna Schwartz and the debt deflation hypothesis of Irving Fisher, Ben Bernanke
developed an alternative way in which the financial crisis affected
output. He builds on Fisher's argument that dramatic declines in the
price level and nominal incomes lead to increasing real debt burdens,
which in turn leads to debtor insolvency and consequently lowers aggregate demand;
a further price level decline would then result in a debt deflationary
spiral. According to Bernanke, a small decline in the price level simply
reallocates wealth from debtors to creditors without doing damage to
the economy. But when the deflation is severe, falling asset prices
along with debtor bankruptcies lead to a decline in the nominal value of
assets on bank balance sheets. Banks will react by tightening their
credit conditions, which in turn leads to a credit crunch
that seriously harms the economy. A credit crunch lowers investment and
consumption, which results in declining aggregate demand and
additionally contributes to the deflationary spiral.[105][106][107]
Expectations hypothesis
Since economic mainstream turned to the new neoclassical synthesis, expectations are a central element of macroeconomic models. According to Peter Temin, Barry Wigmore, Gauti B. Eggertsson and Christina Romer,
the key to recovery and to ending the Great Depression was brought
about by a successful management of public expectations. The thesis is
based on the observation that after years of deflation and a very severe
recession important economic indicators turned positive in March 1933
when Franklin D. Roosevelt
took office. Consumer prices turned from deflation to a mild inflation,
industrial production bottomed out in March 1933, and investment
doubled in 1933 with a turnaround in March 1933. There were no monetary
forces to explain that turnaround. Money supply was still falling and
short-term interest rates remained close to zero. Before March 1933,
people expected further deflation and a recession so that even interest
rates at zero did not stimulate investment. But when Roosevelt announced
major regime changes, people began to expect inflation and an economic
expansion. With these positive expectations, interest rates at zero
began to stimulate investment just as they were expected to do.
Roosevelt's fiscal and monetary policy regime change helped make his
policy objectives credible. The expectation of higher future income and
higher future inflation stimulated demand and investment. The analysis
suggests that the elimination of the policy dogmas of the gold standard,
a balanced budget in times of crisis and small government led
endogenously to a large shift in expectation that accounts for about
70–80% of the recovery of output and prices from 1933 to 1937. If the
regime change had not happened and the Hoover policy had continued, the
economy would have continued its free fall in 1933, and output would
have been 30% lower in 1937 than in 1933.[108][109][110]
The recession of 1937–1938,
which slowed down economic recovery from the Great Depression, is
explained by fears of the population that the moderate tightening of the
monetary and fiscal policy in 1937 were first steps to a restoration of
the pre-1933 policy regime.[111]
Common position
There is common consensus among economists today that the government
and the central bank should work to keep the interconnected
macroeconomic aggregates of gross domestic product and money supply on a stable growth path. When threatened by expectations of a depression, central banks
should expand liquidity in the banking system and the government should
cut taxes and accelerate spending in order to prevent a collapse in
money supply and aggregate demand.[112]
At the beginning of the Great Depression, most economists believed in Say's law and the equilibrating powers of the market, and failed to understand the severity of the Depression. Outright leave-it-alone liquidationism was a common position, and was universally held by Austrian School economists.[113]
The liquidationist position held that a depression worked to liquidate
failed businesses and investments that had been made obsolete by
technological development – releasing factors of production
(capital and labor) to be redeployed in other more productive sectors
of the dynamic economy. They argued that even if self-adjustment of the
economy caused mass bankruptcies, it was still the best course.[113]
Economists like Barry Eichengreen and J. Bradford DeLong note that President Herbert Hoover tried to keep the federal budget balanced until 1932, when he lost confidence in his Secretary of the Treasury Andrew Mellon and replaced him.[113][114][115]
An increasingly common view among economic historians is that the
adherence of many Federal Reserve policymakers to the liquidationist
position led to disastrous consequences.[114]
Unlike what liquidationists expected, a large proportion of the capital
stock was not redeployed but vanished during the first years of the
Great Depression. According to a study by Olivier Blanchard and Lawrence Summers, the recession caused a drop of net capital accumulation to pre-1924 levels by 1933.[116] Milton Friedman called leave-it-alone liquidationism "dangerous nonsense".[112] He wrote:
I think the Austrian business-cycle
theory has done the world a great deal of harm. If you go back to the
1930s, which is a key point, here you had the Austrians sitting in
London, Hayek and Lionel Robbins, and saying you just have to let the
bottom drop out of the world. You've just got to let it cure itself. You
can't do anything about it. You will only make it worse. ... I think by
encouraging that kind of do-nothing policy both in Britain and in the
United States, they did harm.[114]
Heterodox theories
Austrian School
Two prominent theorists in the Austrian School on the Great Depression include Austrian economist Friedrich Hayek and American economist Murray Rothbard, who wrote America's Great Depression (1963). In their view, much like the monetarists, the Federal Reserve (created in 1913) shoulders much of the blame; however, unlike the Monetarists, they argue that the key cause of the Depression was the expansion of the money supply in the 1920s which led to an unsustainable credit-driven boom.[117]
In the Austrian view, it was this inflation of the money supply
that led to an unsustainable boom in both asset prices (stocks and
bonds) and capital goods. Therefore, by the time the Federal Reserve tightened in 1928 it was far too late to prevent an economic contraction.[117] In February 1929 Hayek published a paper predicting the Federal Reserve's actions would lead to a crisis starting in the stock and credit markets.[118]
According to Rothbard, the government support for failed
enterprises and efforts to keep wages above their market values actually
prolonged the Depression.[119] Unlike Rothbard, after 1970 Hayek
believed that the Federal Reserve had further contributed to the
problems of the Depression by permitting the money supply to shrink
during the earliest years of the Depression.[120] However, during the Depression (in 1932[121] and in 1934)[121] Hayek had criticized both the Federal Reserve and the Bank of England for not taking a more contractionary stance.[121]
Ludwig von Mises
wrote in the 1930s: "Credit expansion cannot increase the supply of
real goods. It merely brings about a rearrangement. It diverts capital
investment away from the course prescribed by the state of economic
wealth and market conditions. It causes production to pursue paths which
it would not follow unless the economy were to acquire an increase in
material goods. As a result, the upswing lacks a solid base. It is not
real prosperity. It is illusory prosperity. It did not develop from an
increase in economic wealth, i.e. the accumulation of savings made
available for productive investment. Rather, it arose because the credit
expansion created the illusion of such an increase. Sooner or later, it
must become apparent that this economic situation is built on sand."[123][124]
Marxist
Marxists generally argue that the Great Depression was the result of the inherent instability of the capitalist mode of production.[125] According to Forbes,
"The idea that capitalism caused the Great Depression was widely held
among intellectuals and the general public for many decades."[126]
According to this view, the root cause of the Great Depression
was a global over-investment in heavy industry capacity compared to
wages and earnings from independent businesses, such as farms. The
proposed solution was for the government to pump money into the
consumers' pockets. That is, it must redistribute purchasing power,
maintaining the industrial base, and re-inflating prices and wages to
force as much of the inflationary increase in purchasing power into consumer spending. The economy was overbuilt, and new factories were not needed. Foster and Catchings recommended[129] federal and state governments to start large construction projects, a program followed by Hoover and Roosevelt.
Productivity shock
It cannot be emphasized too
strongly that the [productivity, output, and employment] trends we are
describing are long-time trends and were thoroughly evident before 1929.
These trends are in nowise the result of the present depression, nor
are they the result of the World War. On the contrary, the present
depression is a collapse resulting from these long-term trends.
The first three decades of the 20th century saw economic output surge with electrification, mass production,
and motorized farm machinery, and because of the rapid growth in
productivity there was a lot of excess production capacity and the work
week was being reduced. The dramatic rise in productivity
of major industries in the U.S. and the effects of productivity on
output, wages and the workweek are discussed by Spurgeon Bell in his
book Productivity, Wages, and National Income (1940).[131]
An impoverished American family living in a shanty, 1936
The majority of countries set up relief programs and most underwent some sort of political upheaval, pushing them to the right.
Many of the countries in Europe and Latin America, that were
democracies, saw their democratic governments overthrown by some form of
dictatorship or authoritarian rule, most famously in Germany in 1933. The Dominion of Newfoundland abandoned its autonomy within the British Empire,
becoming the only region ever to voluntarily relinquish democracy.
There, too, were severe impacts across the Middle East and North Africa,
including economic decline which led to social unrest.[132][133]
Decline in foreign trade hit Argentina hard. The British decision to stop importing Argentine beef led to the signing of the Roca–Runciman Treaty,
which preserved a quota in exchange for significant concessions to
British exports. By 1935, the economy had recovered to 1929 levels, and
the same year, the Central Bank of Argentina was formed.[134]
However, the Great Depression was the last time when Argentina was one
of the richer countries of the world, as it stopped growing in the
decades thereafter, and became underdeveloped.[135]
Australia's dependence on agricultural and industrial exports meant it was one of the hardest-hit developed countries.[136]
Falling export demand and commodity prices placed massive downward
pressures on wages. Unemployment reached a record high of 29% in 1932,[137] with incidents of civil unrest becoming common.[138] After 1932, an increase in wool and meat prices led to a gradual recovery.[139]
Harshly affected by both the global economic downturn and the Dust Bowl,
Canadian industrial production had by 1932 fallen to only 58% of its
1929 figure, the second-lowest level in the world after the United
States, and well behind countries such as Britain, which fell to only
83% of the 1929 level. Total national income
fell to 56% of the 1929 level, again worse than any country apart from
the United States. Unemployment reached 27% at the depth of the
Depression in 1933.[140]
The League of Nations labeled Chile
the country hardest-hit by the Great Depression, because 80% of
government revenue came from exports of copper and nitrates, which were
in low demand. Chile initially felt the impact of the Great Depression
in 1930, when GDP dropped 14%, mining income declined 27%, and export
earnings fell 28%. By 1932, GDP had shrunk to less than half of what it
had been in 1929, exacting a terrible toll in unemployment and business
failures.
Influenced profoundly by the Great Depression, many government
leaders promoted the development of local industry in an effort to
insulate the economy from future external shocks. After six years of
government austerity measures,
which succeeded in reestablishing Chile's creditworthiness, Chileans
elected to office during the 1938–58 period a succession of center and
left-of-center governments interested in promoting economic growth
through government intervention.
Prompted in part by the devastating 1939 Chillán earthquake, the Popular Front government of Pedro Aguirre Cerda created the Production Development Corporation (Corporación de Fomento de la Producción, CORFO) to encourage with subsidies and direct investments – an ambitious program of import substitution industrialization. Consequently, as in other Latin American countries, protectionism became an entrenched aspect of the Chilean economy.
China was largely unaffected by the Depression, mainly by having stuck to the Silver standard.
However, the U.S. silver purchase act of 1934 created an intolerable
demand on China's silver coins, and so, in the end, the silver standard
was officially abandoned in 1935 in favor of the four Chinese national
banks'[which?] "legal note" issues. China and the British colony of Hong Kong, which followed suit in this regard in September 1935, would be the last to abandon the silver standard. In addition, the Nationalist Government
also acted energetically to modernize the legal and penal systems,
stabilize prices, amortize debts, reform the banking and currency
systems, build railroads and highways, improve public health facilities,
legislate against traffic in narcotics, and augment industrial and
agricultural production. On 3 November 1935, the government instituted
the fiat currency (fapi) reform, immediately stabilizing prices and also
raising revenues for the government.
European African colonies
The sharp fall in commodity prices and the steep decline in exports
hurt the economies of the European colonies in Africa and Asia.[141][142] The agricultural sector was especially hard-hit. For example, sisal
had recently become a major export crop in Kenya and Tanganyika. During
the depression, it suffered severely from low prices and marketing
problems that affected all colonial commodities in Africa. Sisal
producers established centralized controls for the export of their
fibre.[143] There was widespread unemployment and hardship among peasants, labourers, colonial auxiliaries, and artisans.[144]
The budgets of colonial governments were cut, which forced the
reduction in ongoing infrastructure projects, such as the building and
upgrading of roads, ports, and communications.[145] The budget cuts delayed the schedule for creating systems of higher education.[146]
The depression severely hurt the export-based Belgian Congo
economy because of the drop in international demand for raw materials
and for agricultural products. For example, the price of peanuts fell
from 125 to 25 centimes. In some areas, as in the Katanga
mining region, employment declined by 70%. In the country as a whole,
the wage labour force decreased by 72,000 people, and many men returned
to their villages. In Leopoldville, the population decreased by 33%
because of this labour migration.[147]
Political protests were not common. However, there was a growing
demand, that the paternalistic claims be honored by colonial governments
to respond vigorously. The theme was, that economic reforms were more
urgently needed than political reforms.[148]
French West Africa launched an extensive program of educational reform,
in which "rural schools", designed to modernize agriculture, would stem
the flow of under-employed farm workers to cities where unemployment
was high. Students were trained in traditional arts, crafts, and farming
techniques and were then expected to return to their own villages and
towns.[149]
The crisis affected France a bit later than other countries, hitting hard around 1931.[150] While the 1920s grew at the very strong rate of 4.43% per year, the 1930s rate fell to only 0.63%.[151]
The depression was relatively mild: unemployment peaked under 5%,
the fall in production was at most 20% below the 1929 output; there was
no banking crisis.[152]
However, the depression had drastic effects on the local economy, and partly explains the February 6, 1934 riots and even more the formation of the Popular Front, led by SFIO socialist leaderLéon Blum, which won the elections in 1936. Ultra-nationalist groups also saw increased popularity, though democracy prevailed into World War II.
France's relatively high degree of self-sufficiency meant the
damage was considerably less than in neighbouring states like Germany.
The Great Depression hit Germany hard. The impact of the Wall Street crash forced American banks to end the new loans that had been funding the repayments under the Dawes Plan and the Young Plan. The financial crisis escalated out of control in mid-1931, starting with the collapse of the Credit Anstalt in Vienna in May.[42] This put heavy pressure on Germany, which was already in political turmoil with the rise in violence of national socialist and communist movements, as well as with investor nervousness at harsh government financial policies,[43]
investors withdrew their short-term money from Germany as confidence
spiraled downward. The Reichsbank lost 150 million marks in the first
week of June, 540 million in the second, and 150 million in two days,
19–20 June. Collapse was at hand. U.S. President Herbert Hoover called
for a moratorium on payment of war reparations. This angered Paris,
which depended on a steady flow of German payments, but it slowed the
crisis down, and the moratorium was agreed to in July 1931. An
international conference in London later in July produced no agreements,
but on 19 August, a standstill agreement froze Germany's foreign
liabilities for six months. Germany received emergency funding from
private banks in New York as well as the Bank of International
Settlements and the Bank of England. The funding only slowed the
process. Industrial failures began in Germany, a major bank closed in
July, and a two-day holiday for all German banks was declared. Business
failures became more frequent in July, and spread to Romania and
Hungary.[44]
In 1932, 90% of German reparation payments were cancelled (in the
1950s, Germany repaid all its missed reparations debts). Widespread
unemployment reached 25%, as every sector was hurt. The government did
not increase government spending to deal with Germany's growing crisis,
as they were afraid that a high-spending policy could lead to a return
of the hyperinflation that had affected Germany in 1923. Germany's Weimar Republic was hit hard by the depression, as American loans to help rebuild the German economy now stopped.[153] The unemployment rate reached nearly 30% in 1932.[154]
The devil operating a screw press against a workman, Nazi propaganda medal, obverseThe reverse of this medal supporting the German election Nazi campaigns of 1932
The German political landscape was dramatically altered, leading to Adolf Hitler's rise to power. The Nazi Party rose from being peripheral to winning 18.3% of the vote in the September 1930 election, and the Communist Party also made gains, while moderate forces, like the Social Democratic Party, the Democratic Party, and the People's Party
lost seats. The next two years were marked by increased street violence
between Nazis and Communists, while governments under President Paul von Hindenburg increasingly relied on rule by decree, bypassing the Reichstag.[155]
Hitler ran for the Presidency in 1932, and while he lost to the
incumbent Hindenburg in the election, it marked a point during which
both Nazi Party and the Communist parties rose in the years following
the crash to altogether possess a Reichstag majority following the general election in July 1932.[154][156] Although the Nazis lost seats in November 1932 election,
they remained the largest party, and Hitler was appointed as Chancellor
the following January. The government formation deal was designed to
give Hitler's conservative coalition partners many checks on his power,
but over the next few months, the Nazis manoeuvred to consolidate a
single-party dictatorship.[157]
Hitler followed an economic policy of autarky,
creating a network of client states and economic allies in central
Europe and Latin America. By cutting wages and taking control of labor
unions, plus public works spending, unemployment fell significantly by
1935. Large-scale military spending played a major role in the recovery.[158]
The policies had the effect of driving up the cost of food imports and
depleting foreign currency reserves, leading to economic impasse by
1936. Nazi Germany faced a choice of either reversing course or pressing
ahead with rearmament and autarky. Hitler chose the latter route,
which, according to Ian Kershaw, "could only be partially accomplished without territorial expansion" and therefore war.[159][160]
The reverberations of the Great Depression hit Greece in 1932. The Bank of Greece
tried to adopt deflationary policies to stave off the crises that were
going on in other countries, but these largely failed. For a brief
period, the drachma was pegged to the U.S. dollar, but this was
unsustainable given the country's large trade deficit and the only
long-term effects of this were Greece's foreign exchange reserves being
almost totally wiped out in 1932. Remittances from abroad declined
sharply, and the value of the drachma began to plummet from 77 drachmas
to the dollar in March 1931 to 111 drachmas to the dollar in April 1931.
This was especially harmful to Greece, as the country relied on imports
from the UK, France, and the Middle East for many necessities. Greece
went off the gold standard in April 1932, and declared a moratorium on
all interest payments. The country also adopted protectionist policies,
such as import quotas, which several European countries also did during
the period.
Protectionist policies coupled with a weak drachma and the
stifling of imports allowed the Greek industry to expand during the
Great Depression. In 1939, the Greek industrial output was 179% that of
1928. These industries were for the most part "built on sand", as one
report of the Bank of Greece put it, as without massive protection, they
would not have been able to survive. Despite the global depression,
Greece managed to suffer comparatively little, averaging an average
growth rate of 3.5% from 1932 to 1939. The dictatorial regime of Ioannis Metaxas took over the Greek government in 1936, and economic growth was strong in the years leading up to the Second World War.
Icelandic post-World War I prosperity came to an end with the
outbreak of the Great Depression. The Depression hit Iceland hard, as
the value of exports plummeted. The total value of Icelandic exports
fell from 74 million kronur in 1929 to 48 million in 1932, and was not
to rise again to the pre-1930 level until after 1939.[161]
Government interference in the economy increased: "Imports were
regulated, trade with foreign currency was monopolized by state-owned
banks, and loan capital was largely distributed by state-regulated
funds".[161] Due to the outbreak of the Spanish Civil War,
which cut Iceland's exports of saltfish by half, the Depression lasted
in Iceland until the outbreak of World War II (when prices for fish
exports soared).[161]
How much India was affected, has been hotly debated. Historians have
argued, that the Great Depression slowed long-term industrial
development.[162] Apart from two sectors – jute
and coal – the economy was little-affected. However, there were major
negative impacts on the jute industry, as world demand fell and prices
plunged.[163] Otherwise, conditions were fairly stable. Local markets in agriculture and small-scale industry showed modest gains.[164]
Ireland was a largely agrarian economy, trading almost
exclusively with the UK at the time of the Great Depression. Beef and
dairy products comprised the bulk of exports, and Ireland fared well
relative to many other commodity producers, particularly in the early
years of the depression.[165][166][167][168]
Unemployed outside a factory in Italy, October 1931Benito Mussolini giving a speech at the FiatLingotto factory in Turin, 1932
The Great Depression hit Italy very hard.[169]
As industries came close to failure they were bought out by the banks
in a largely illusionary bail-out—the assets used to fund the purchases
were largely worthless. This led to a financial crisis peaking in 1932
and major government intervention. The Industrial Reconstruction Institute
(IRI) was formed in January 1933 and took control of the bank-owned
companies, suddenly giving Italy the largest state-owned industrial
sector in Europe (excluding the USSR). IRI did rather well with its new
responsibilities—restructuring, modernising and rationalising as much as
it could. It was a significant factor in post-1945 development. But it
took the Italian economy until 1935 to recover the manufacturing levels
of 1930—a position that was only 60% better than that of 1913.[170][171]
Japan
The Great Depression did not strongly affect Japan. The Japanese economy shrank by 8% during 1929–31. Japan's Finance Minister Takahashi Korekiyo was the first to implement what have come to be identified as Keynesian economic policies: first, by large fiscal stimulus involving deficit spending; and second, by devaluing the currency.
Takahashi used the Bank of Japan to sterilize the deficit spending and
minimize resulting inflationary pressures. Econometric studies have
identified the fiscal stimulus as especially effective.[172]
The devaluation of the currency had an immediate effect. Japanese
textiles began to displace British textiles in export markets. The
deficit spending proved to be most profound and went into the purchase
of munitions for the armed forces. By 1933, Japan was already out of the
depression. By 1934, Takahashi realized that the economy was in danger
of overheating, and to avoid inflation, moved to reduce the deficit
spending that went towards armaments and munitions.
This resulted in a strong and swift negative reaction from
nationalists, especially those in the army, culminating in his
assassination in the course of the February 26 Incident. This had a chilling effect
on all civilian bureaucrats in the Japanese government. From 1934, the
military's dominance of the government continued to grow. Instead of
reducing deficit spending, the government introduced price controls and
rationing schemes that reduced, but did not eliminate inflation, which
remained a problem until the end of World War II.
The deficit spending had a transformative effect on Japan.
Japan's industrial production doubled during the 1930s. Further, in 1929
the list of the largest firms in Japan was dominated by light
industries, especially textile companies (many of Japan's automakers,
such as Toyota, have their roots in the textile industry). By 1940 light industry had been displaced by heavy industry as the largest firms inside the Japanese economy.[173]
Because of high levels of U.S. investment in Latin American
economies, they were severely damaged by the Depression. Within the
region, Chile, Bolivia and Peru were particularly badly affected.[174]
Before the 1929 crisis, links between the world economy and Latin American
economies had been established through American and British investment
in Latin American exports to the world. As a result, Latin Americans
export industries felt the depression quickly. World prices for
commodities such as wheat, coffee and copper plunged. Exports from all
of Latin America to the U.S. fell in value from $1.2 billion in 1929 to
$335 million in 1933, rising to $660 million in 1940.
But on the other hand, the depression led the area governments to
develop new local industries and expand consumption and production.
Following the example of the New Deal, governments in the area approved
regulations and created or improved welfare institutions that helped
millions of new industrial workers to achieve a better standard of
living.
From roughly 1931 to 1937, the Netherlands
suffered a deep and exceptionally long depression. This depression was
partly caused by the after-effects of the American stock-market crash of
1929, and partly by internal factors in the Netherlands. Government
policy, especially the very late dropping of the Gold Standard, played a
role in prolonging the depression. The Great Depression in the
Netherlands led to some political instability and riots, and can be
linked to the rise of the Dutch fascist political party NSB.
The depression in the Netherlands eased off somewhat at the end of
1936, when the government finally dropped the Gold Standard, but real
economic stability did not return until after World War II.[175]
New Zealand
was especially vulnerable to worldwide depression, as it relied almost
entirely on agricultural exports to the United Kingdom for its economy.
The drop in exports led to a lack of disposable income from the farmers,
who were the mainstay of the local economy. Jobs disappeared and wages
plummeted, leaving people desperate and charities unable to cope. Work
relief schemes were the only government support available to the
unemployed, the rate of which by the early 1930s was officially around
15%, but unofficially nearly twice that level (official figures excluded
Māori and women). In 1932, riots occurred among the unemployed in three
of the country's main cities (Auckland, Dunedin, and Wellington).
Many were arrested or injured through the tough official handling of
these riots by police and volunteer "special constables".[176]
Poland was affected by the Great Depression longer and stronger than
other countries due to inadequate economic response of the government
and the pre-existing economic circumstances of the country. At that
time, Poland was under the authoritarian rule of Sanacja, whose leader, Józef Piłsudski, was opposed to leaving the gold standard
until his death in 1935. As a result, Poland was unable to perform a
more active monetary and budget policy. Additionally, Poland was a
relatively young country that emerged merely 10 years earlier after
being partitioned between German, Russian, and the Austro-Hungarian Empires
for over a century. Prior to independence, the Russian part exported
91% of its exports to Russia proper, while the German part exported 68%
to Germany proper. After independence, these markets were largely lost,
as Russia transformed into USSR that was mostly a closed economy, and Germany was in a tariff war with Poland throughout the 1920s.[178]
Industrial production fell significantly: in 1932 hard coal production was down 27% compared to 1928, steel production was down 61%, and iron ore production noted an 89% decrease.[179]
On the other hand, electrotechnical, leather, and paper industries
noted marginal increases in production output. Overall, industrial
production decreased by 41%.[180]
A distinct feature of the Great Depression in Poland was the
de-concentration of industry, as larger conglomerates were less flexible
and paid their workers more than smaller ones.
Unemployment rate rose significantly (up to 43%) while nominal wages
fell by 51% in 1933 and 56% in 1934, relative to 1928. However, real
wages fell less due to the government's policy of decreasing cost of
living, particularly food expenditures (food prices were down by 65% in
1935 compared to 1928 price levels). Material conditions deprivation led
to strikes, some of them violent or violently pacified – like in Sanok (March of the Hungry in Sanok [pl] 6 March 1930), Lesko county (Lesko uprising 21 June – 9 July 1932) and Zawiercie (Bloody Friday (1930) [pl] 18 April 1930).
To adapt to the crisis, Polish government employed deflation methods such as high interest rates, credit limits and budget austerity to keep a fixed exchange rate with currencies tied to the gold standard. Only in late 1932 did the government effect a plan to fight the economic crisis.[181] Part of the plan was mass public works scheme, employing up to 100,000 people in 1935.[179] After Piłsudski's death, in 1936 the gold standard regime was relaxed, and launching the development of the Central Industrial Region kicked off the economy, to over 10% annual growth rate in the 1936–1938 period.
Already under the rule of a dictatorial junta, the Ditadura Nacional, Portugal suffered no turbulent political effects of the Depression, although António de Oliveira Salazar, already appointed Minister of Finance in 1928 greatly expanded his powers and in 1932 rose to Prime Minister of Portugal to found the Estado Novo, an authoritariancorporatist dictatorship. With the budget balanced in 1929, the effects of the depression were relaxed through harsh measures towards budget balance and autarky, causing social discontent but stability and, eventually, an impressive economic growth.[182]
Puerto Rico
In the years immediately preceding the depression, negative
developments in the island and world economies perpetuated an
unsustainable cycle of subsistence for many Puerto Rican workers. The
1920s brought a dramatic drop in Puerto Rico's two primary exports, raw
sugar and coffee, due to a devastating hurricane in 1928 and the
plummeting demand from global markets in the latter half of the decade.
1930 unemployment on the island was roughly 36% and by 1933 Puerto
Rico's per capita income dropped 30% (by comparison, unemployment in the
United States in 1930 was approximately 8% reaching a height of 25% in
1933).[183][184] To provide relief and economic reform, the United States government and Puerto Rican politicians such as Carlos Chardon and Luis Muñoz Marín created and administered first the Puerto Rico Emergency Relief Administration (PRERA) 1933 and then in 1935, the Puerto Rico Reconstruction Administration (PRRA).[185]
As world trade slumped, demand for South African agricultural and mineral exports fell drastically. The Carnegie Commission on Poor Whites had concluded in 1931 that nearly one-third of Afrikaners
lived as paupers. The social discomfort caused by the depression was a
contributing factor in the 1933 split between the "gesuiwerde"
(purified) and "smelter" (fusionist) factions within the National Party and the National Party's subsequent fusion with the South African Party.[188][189] Unemployment programs were begun that focused primarily on the white population.[190]
Soviet Union
The Soviet Union was the only major socialist state
in the world and had very little international trade. Its economy was
not tied to the rest of the world and was mostly unaffected by the Great
Depression.[191]
At the time of the Depression, the Soviet economy was growing
steadily, fuelled by intensive investment in heavy industry. The
apparent economic success of the Soviet Union at a time when the
capitalist world was in crisis led many Western intellectuals to view
the Soviet system favorably. Jennifer Burns wrote:
As the Great Depression ground on
and unemployment soared, intellectuals began unfavorably comparing their
faltering capitalist economy to Russian Communism. Karl Marx had
predicted that capitalism would fall under the weight of its own
contradictions, and now with the economic crisis gripping the West, his
predictions seem to be coming true. By contrast Russia seemed an
emblematic modern nation, making the staggering leap from a feudal past
to an industrial future with ease.[192]
The early years of the Great Depression caused mass immigration to
the Soviet Union, including 10,000 to 15,000 from Finland and thousands
more from Poland, Sweden, Germany, and other nearby countries. The
Kremlin was at first happy to help these immigrants settle, believing
that they were victims of capitalism who had come to help the Soviet
cause. However, by 1933, the worst of the Depression had come to an end
in many countries, and word had been received that illegal migrants to
the Soviet Union were being sent to Siberia.[citation needed]
These factors caused immigration to the Soviet Union to slow
significantly, and roughly a tenth of Finnish migrants returned to
Finland, either legally or illegally.[193]
Spain had a relatively isolated economy, with high protective tariffs
and was not one of the main countries affected by the Depression. The
banking system held up well, as did agriculture.[194]
By far the most serious negative impact came after 1936 from the heavy destruction of infrastructure and manpower by the civil war, 1936–39. Many talented workers were forced into permanent exile. By staying neutral in the Second World War, and selling to both sides[clarification needed], the economy avoided further disasters.[195]
By the 1930s, Sweden had what America's Life magazine
called in 1938 the "world's highest standard of living". Sweden was
also the first country worldwide to recover completely from the Great
Depression. Taking place amid a short-lived government and a
less-than-a-decade old Swedish democracy, events such as those
surrounding Ivar Kreuger (who eventually committed suicide) remain infamous in Swedish history. The Social Democrats under Per Albin Hansson formed their first long-lived government in 1932 based on strong interventionist and welfare state policies, monopolizing the office of Prime Minister until 1976 with the sole and short-lived exception of Axel Pehrsson-Bramstorp's
"summer cabinet" in 1936. During forty years of hegemony, it was the
most successful political party in the history of Western liberal
democracy.[196]
The Great Depression came at a time when the relatively newly
established Turkish state was still reforming its economic policy
following the end of the Ottoman
era. As the depression began, the country's trade deficits saw an
increase and the Turkish lira significantly lost value. Turkey's economy
was predominantly agrarian, thus the fall in demand which caused a fall
in export prices of many goods affected the country's economy badly. As
a result of the depression, the government, which had been following
increasingly more liberal economic policies up until then, started
opting for more statist policies.[198]
Unemployed people in front of a workhouse in London, 1930
The world depression broke at a time when the United Kingdom had still not fully recovered from the effects of the First World War more than a decade earlier. The country was driven off the gold standard in 1931.
The world financial crisis began to overwhelm Britain in 1931;
investors around the world started withdrawing their gold from London at
the rate of £2.5 million per day.[45]
Credits of £25 million each from the Bank of France and the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York and an issue of £15 million fiduciary note
slowed, but did not reverse the British crisis. The financial crisis now
caused a major political crisis in Britain in August 1931. With
deficits mounting, the bankers demanded a balanced budget; the divided
cabinet of Prime Minister Ramsay MacDonald's Labour government agreed;
it proposed to raise taxes, cut spending and most controversially, to
cut unemployment benefits by 20%. The attack on welfare was totally
unacceptable to the Labour movement. MacDonald wanted to resign, but
King George V insisted he remain and form an all-party coalition "National Government".
The Conservative and Liberals parties signed on, along with a small
cadre of Labour, but the vast majority of Labour leaders denounced
MacDonald as a traitor for leading the new government. Britain went off
the gold standard, and suffered relatively less than other major
countries in the Great Depression. In the 1931 British election, the
Labour Party was virtually destroyed, leaving MacDonald as prime
minister for a largely Conservative coalition.[199][47]
The effects on the northern industrial areas of Britain were
immediate and devastating, as demand for traditional industrial products
collapsed. By the end of 1930 unemployment had more than doubled from
1 million to 2.5 million (20% of the insured workforce), and exports had
fallen in value by 50%. In 1933, 30% of Glaswegians
were unemployed due to the severe decline in heavy industry. In some
towns and cities in the north east, unemployment reached as high as 70%
as shipbuilding fell by 90%.[200] The National Hunger March of September–October 1932 was the largest[201] of a series of hunger marches
in Britain in the 1920s and 1930s. About 200,000 unemployed men were
sent to the work camps, which continued in operation until 1939.[202]
In the less industrial Midlands and Southern England,
the effects were short-lived and the later 1930s were a prosperous
time. Growth in modern manufacture of electrical goods and a boom in the
motor car industry was helped by a growing southern population and an
expanding middle class. Agriculture also saw a boom during this period.[203]
Unemployed men standing in line outside a depression soup kitchen in Chicago, 1931
Hoover's first measures to combat the depression were based on
encouraging businesses not to reduce their workforce or cut wages but
businesses had little choice: wages were reduced, workers were laid off,
and investments postponed.[204][205]
In June 1930, Congress approved the Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act
which raised tariffs on thousands of imported items. The intent of the
Act was to encourage the purchase of American-made products by
increasing the cost of imported goods, while raising revenue for the
federal government and protecting farmers. Most countries that traded
with the U.S. increased tariffs on American-made goods in retaliation,
reducing international trade, and worsening the Depression.[206]
In 1931, Hoover urged bankers to set up the National Credit Corporation[207]
so that big banks could help failing banks survive. But bankers were
reluctant to invest in failing banks, and the National Credit
Corporation did almost nothing to address the problem.[208]
Burning shacks on the Anacostia flats, Washington, D.C., put up by the Bonus Army (World War I veterans) after the marchers with their wives and children were driven out by the regular Army by order of President Hoover, 1932[209]
By 1932, unemployment had reached 23.6%, peaking in early 1933 at 25%.[210]
Those released from prison during this period had an especially
difficult time finding employment given the stigma of their criminal
records, which often led to recidivism out of economic desperation.[211]
Drought persisted in the agricultural heartland, businesses and
families defaulted on record numbers of loans, and more than 5,000 banks
had failed.[212] Hundreds of thousands of Americans found themselves homeless, and began congregating in shanty towns – dubbed "Hoovervilles" – that began to appear across the country.[213] In response, President Hoover and Congress approved the Federal Home Loan Bank Act,
to spur new home construction, and reduce foreclosures. The final
attempt of the Hoover Administration to stimulate the economy was the
passage of the Emergency Relief and Construction Act (ERA) which included funds for public works programs such as dams and the creation of the Reconstruction Finance Corporation
(RFC) in 1932. The Reconstruction Finance Corporation was a Federal
agency with the authority to lend up to $2 billion to rescue banks and
restore confidence in financial institutions. But $2 billion was not
enough to save all the banks, and bank runs and bank failures continued.[204] Quarter by quarter the economy went downhill, as prices, profits and employment fell, leading to the political realignment in 1932 that brought to power Franklin Delano Roosevelt.
Buried machinery in a barn lot; South Dakota, May 1936. The Dust Bowl on the Great Plains coincided with the Great Depression.[214]
Shortly after President Franklin Delano Roosevelt was inaugurated in 1933, drought and erosion combined to cause the Dust Bowl, shifting hundreds of thousands of displaced persons
off their farms in the Midwest. From his inauguration onward, Roosevelt
argued that restructuring of the economy would be needed to prevent
another depression or avoid prolonging the current one. New Deal
programs sought to stimulate demand
and provide work and relief for the impoverished through increased
government spending and the institution of financial reforms.
CCC
workers constructing drainage culvert, 1933. Over 3 million unemployed
young men were taken out of the cities and placed into 2,600+ work camps
managed by the CCC.[215]
These reforms, together with several other relief and recovery measures, are called the First New Deal. Economic stimulus was attempted through a new alphabet soup of agencies set up in 1933 and 1934 and previously extant agencies such as the Reconstruction Finance Corporation. By 1935, the "Second New Deal" added Social Security (which was later considerably extended through the Fair Deal), a jobs program for the unemployed (the Works Progress Administration, WPA) and, through the National Labor Relations Board, a strong stimulus to the growth of labor unions. In 1929, federal expenditures constituted only 3% of the GDP.
The national debt as a proportion of GNP rose under Hoover from 20% to
40%. Roosevelt kept it at 40% until the war began, when it soared to
128%.
By 1936, the main economic indicators
had regained the levels of the late 1920s, except for unemployment,
which remained high at 11%, although this was considerably lower than
the 25% unemployment rate seen in 1933. In the spring of 1937, American
industrial production exceeded that of 1929 and remained level until
June 1937. In June 1937, the Roosevelt administration cut spending and
increased taxation in an attempt to balance the federal budget.[216]
The American economy then took a sharp downturn, lasting for 13 months
through most of 1938. Industrial production fell almost 30% within a few
months and production of durable goods
fell even faster. Unemployment jumped from 14.3% in 1937 to 19.0% in
1938, rising from 5 million to more than 12 million in early 1938.[217] Manufacturing output fell by 37% from the 1937 peak and was back to 1934 levels.[218]
Producers reduced their expenditures on durable goods, and
inventories declined, but personal income was only 15% lower than it had
been at the peak in 1937. As unemployment rose, consumers' expenditures
declined, leading to further cutbacks in production. By May 1938 retail
sales began to increase, employment improved, and industrial production
turned up after June 1938.[219] After the recovery from the Recession of 1937–38, conservatives were able to form a bipartisan conservative coalition
to stop further expansion of the New Deal and, when unemployment
dropped to 2% in the early 1940s, they abolished WPA, CCC and the PWA
relief programs. Social Security remained in place.
Between 1933 and 1939, federal expenditure tripled, and Roosevelt's critics charged that he was turning America into a socialist state.[220] The Great Depression was a main factor in the implementation of social democracy and planned economies in European countries after World War II (see Marshall Plan). Keynesianism
generally remained the most influential economic school in the United
States and in parts of Europe until the periods between the 1970s and
the 1980s, when Milton Friedman and other neoliberal economists formulated and propagated the newly created theories of neoliberalism and incorporated them into the Chicago School of Economics
as an alternative approach to the study of economics. Neoliberalism
went on to challenge the dominance of the Keynesian school of Economics
in the mainstream academia and policy-making in the United States,
having reached its peak in popularity in the election of the presidency
of Ronald Reagan in the United States, and Margaret Thatcher in the United Kingdom.[221]
Literature
And the great owners, who must lose their land in an upheaval, the
great owners with access to history, with eyes to read history and to
know the great fact: when property accumulates in too few hands it is
taken away. And that companion fact: when a majority of the people are
hungry and cold they will take by force what they need. And the little
screaming fact that sounds through all history: repression works only to
strengthen and knit the repressed.
The Great Depression has been the subject of much writing, as authors
have sought to evaluate an era that caused both financial and emotional
trauma. Perhaps the most noteworthy and famous novel written on the
subject is The Grapes of Wrath, published in 1939 and written by John Steinbeck, who was awarded the Pulitzer Prize for the work, and in 1962 was awarded the Nobel Prize
for literature. The novel focuses on a poor family of sharecroppers who
are forced from their home as drought, economic hardship, and changes
in the agricultural industry occur during the Great Depression. Steinbeck's Of Mice and Men is another important novella about a journey during the Great Depression. Additionally, Harper Lee's To Kill a Mockingbird is set during the Great Depression. Margaret Atwood's Booker prize-winning The Blind Assassin
is likewise set in the Great Depression, centering on a privileged
socialite's love affair with a Marxist revolutionary. The era spurred
the resurgence of social realism, practiced by many who started their
writing careers on relief programs, especially the Federal Writers' Project in the U.S.[223][224][225][226] Nonfiction works from this time also capture important themes. The 1933 memoir Prison Days and Nights by Victor Folke Nelson
provides insight into criminal justice ramifications of the Great
Depression, especially in regard to patterns of recidivism due to lack
of economic opportunity.[211]
A number of works for younger audiences are also set during the Great Depression, among them the Kit Kittredge series of American Girl books written by Valerie Tripp and illustrated by Walter Rane,
released to tie in with the dolls and playsets sold by the company. The
stories, which take place during the early to mid 1930s in Cincinnati, focuses on the changes brought by the Depression to the titular character's family and how the Kittredges dealt with it.[227] A theatrical adaptation of the series entitled Kit Kittredge: An American Girl was later released in 2008 to positive reviews.[228][229] Similarly, Christmas After All, part of the Dear America series of books for older girls, take place in 1930s Indianapolis; while Kit Kittredge is told in a third-person viewpoint, Christmas After All
is in the form of a fictional journal as told by the protagonist Minnie
Swift as she recounts her experiences during the era, especially when
her family takes in an orphan cousin from Texas.[230]
The term "The Great Depression" is most frequently attributed to British economist Lionel Robbins, whose 1934 book The Great Depression is credited with formalizing the phrase,[231] though Hoover is widely credited with popularizing the term,[231][232]
informally referring to the downturn as a depression, with such uses as
"Economic depression cannot be cured by legislative action or executive
pronouncement" (December 1930, Message to Congress), and "I need not
recount to you that the world is passing through a great depression"
(1931).
The term "depression"
to refer to an economic downturn dates to the 19th century, when it was
used by varied Americans and British politicians and economists. The
first major American economic crisis, the Panic of 1819, was described by then-president James Monroe as "a depression",[231] and the most recent economic crisis, the Depression of 1920–21, had been referred to as a "depression" by then-president Calvin Coolidge.
Financial crises were traditionally referred to as "panics", most recently the major Panic of 1907, and the minor Panic of 1910–11,
though the 1929 crisis was called "The Crash", and the term "panic" has
since fallen out of use. At the time of the Great Depression, the term
"The Great Depression" was already used to refer to the period 1873–96
(in the United Kingdom), or more narrowly 1873–79 (in the United
States), which has retroactively been renamed the Long Depression.[233]
1928 and 1929 were the times in the 20th century that the wealth gap reached such skewed extremes;[243]
half the unemployed had been out of work for over six months, something
that was not repeated until the late-2000s recession. 2007 and 2008
eventually saw the world reach new levels of wealth gap inequality that
rivalled the years of 1928 and 1929.
Friedman, Milton; Schwartz, Anna Jacobson (2008). A monetary history of the United States 1867–1960. Princeton paperbacks (9th pbk. printing, 22nd printing ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN978-0-691-00354-2.
Lewis, William Arthur (2003). Economic survey: 1919–1939. International economics (Reprint [der Ausg.] 1949 ed.). London [u.a.]: Routledge. ISBN978-0-415-31359-9.
Frank, Robert H.; Bernanke, Ben S. (2007). Principles of Macroeconomics (3rd ed.). Boston: McGraw-Hill/Irwin. p. 98. ISBN978-0-07-319397-7.
"Commodity Data". U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Archived from the original on 3 June 2019. Retrieved 30 November 2008.
Thomas S. Coleman (2019). Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz, and A Monetary History of the US. Draft Lecture, Harris School of Public Policy, University of Chicago.
Kindleberger, Charles P. (1986). The world in depression, 1929–1939. History of the world economy in the twentieth century (Rev. and enl. ed.). Berkeley: University of California Press. ISBN978-0-520-05591-9.
Kindleberger, Charles Poor (1973). The world in depression, 1929–1939.
History of the world economy in the twentieth century (Rev. and enl.
ed., 11. [print.] ed.). Berkeley, Calif.: University of California
Press. ISBN978-0-520-05592-6.
Richard, Clay Hanes, ed. (July 2002). Historic Events for Students: The Great Depression (Volume I ed.). Gale. ISBN978-0-7876-5701-7.
Tignor, Robert L. (28 October 2013). Worlds together, worlds apart: a history of the world from the beginnings of humankind to the present (Fourth ed.). New York: W. W. Norton. ISBN978-0-393-92207-3. OCLC854609153.
According
to the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Data website, based
on a monthly timeseries 1929 September – 1932 June, the Dow Jones
Industrial Average lost 87.1% while the Cowles Commission and S&P's
all stock index lost 85.0%: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=qj2m , https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=qj2l.
Whaples,
Robert (1995). "Where is There Consensus Among American Economic
Historians? The Results of a Survey on Forty Propositions". The Journal of Economic History. 55 (1): 139–154. doi:10.1017/S0022050700040602. JSTOR2123771. S2CID145691938.
"The Mistake of 1937: A General Equilibrium Analysis", Monetary and Economic Studies 24, No. S-1 (December 2006), Boj.or.jpArchived 11 August 2015 at the Wayback Machine
Steven Horwitz, "Unfortunately Unfamiliar with Robert Higgs and Others: A Rejoinder to Gauti Eggertsson on the 1930s", Econ Journal Watch 8(1), 2, January 2011. [1]Archived 15 February 2022 at the Wayback Machine.
Ben Bernanke. Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton University Press. ISBN978-0-691-01698-6. p. 7
Ben S. Bernanke, "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propaga-tion of the Great Depression", The American Economic Review 73, No. 3 (June 1983): 257–276, available from the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank collection at Stlouisfed.orgArchived 5 March 2016 at the Wayback Machine
Ann E. McCleary, "'I Was Really Proud of Them': Canned Raspberries and Home Production During the Farm Depression". Augusta Historical Bulletin (2010), Issue 46, pp. 14–44.
Baillargeon, Making Do: Women, Family and Home in Montreal during the Great Depression (1999), pp. 70, 108, 136–138, 159.
Metzler, Mark (2004). "Woman's Place in Japan's Great Depression: Reflections on the Moral Economy of Deflation". Journal of Japanese Studies. 30 (2): 315–352. doi:10.1353/jjs.2004.0045. S2CID146273711.
Reagin,
N. R. (2001). "Marktordnung and Autarkic Housekeeping: Housewives and
Private Consumption under the Four-Year Plan, 1936–1939". German History. 19 (2): 162–184. doi:10.1191/026635501678771619. PMID19610237.
Romer, Christina D. (1992). "What Ended the Great Depression?". Journal of Economic History. 52 (4): 757–784. doi:10.1017/S002205070001189X. fiscal
policy was of little consequence even as late as 1942, suggests an
interesting twist on the usual view that World War II caused, or at
least accelerated, the recovery from the Great Depression.
Klein, Lawrence R. (1947), The Keynesian Revolution, New York: Macmillan, pp. 56–58, 169, 177–179; Rosenof, Theodore (1997). Economics in the Long Run: New Deal Theorists and Their Legacies, 1933–1993. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. ISBN0-8078-2315-5.
Fisher, Irving (October 1933). "The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions". Econometrica. 1 (4). The Econometric Society: 337–57. doi:10.2307/1907327. JSTOR1907327. S2CID35564016.
Mishkin, Fredric (December 1978). "The Household Balance and the Great Depression". Journal of Economic History. 38 (4): 918–937. doi:10.1017/S0022050700087167. S2CID155049545.
Diego Pizano, Conversations with Great Economists: Friedrich
A. Hayek, John Hicks, Nicholas Kaldor, Leonid V. Kantorovich, Joan
Robinson, Paul A.Samuelson, Jan Tinbergen (Jorge Pinto Books, 2009).
For Rothbard's view, see:
Murray Rothbard, A History of Money and Banking in the United States (Ludwig von Mises Institute), pp. 293–294.
Foster, William Trufant; Catchings, Waddill (1928). The Road to Plenty. Houghton Mifflin. Archived from the original on 18 February 2022. Retrieved 28 December 2021.
James Overton, "Economic Crisis and the End of Democracy: Politics in Newfoundland During the Great Depression." Labour 1990 (26): 85–124. ISSN0700-3862
Anthony Latham and John Heaton, The Depression and the Developing World, 1914–1939 (1981).
Coquery-Vidrovitch, C. (1977). "Mutation de l'Impérialisme Colonial Français dans les Années 30". African Economic History (in French) (4): 103–152. doi:10.2307/3601244. JSTOR3601244.
Westcott,
Nicholas (1984). "The East African sisal industry, 1929–1949: the
marketing of a colonial commodity during depression and war". Journal of African History. 25 (4): 445–461. doi:10.1017/s0021853700028486. S2CID161203218.
R. Olufeni Ekundare, An Economic History of Nigeria 1860–1960 (1973) online. Archived 31 December 2021 at the Wayback Machine, pp. 104–226.
Olubomehin, O.O. (2002). "Road Transportation and the Economy of South-Western Nigeria, 1920–1939". Lagos Historical Review. 2: 106–121.
Lungu,
Gatian F. (1993). "Educational Policy-Making in Colonial Zambia: The
Case of Higher Education for Africans from 1924 to 1964". The Journal of Negro History. 78 (4): 207–232. doi:10.2307/2717416. JSTOR2717416. S2CID149538992.
R. Anstey, King Leopold's Legacy: The Congo under Belgian Rule 1908–1960 (1966), p. 109.
Ochonu,
Moses (2009). "Critical convergence: the Great Depression and the
meshing of Nigerian and British anti-colonial polemic". Canadian Journal of African Studies. 43 (2): 245–281. doi:10.1080/00083968.2010.9707572. S2CID142695035.
Adam Tooze, The Wages of Destruction: The Making and Breaking of the Nazi Economy (2007)
R. J. Overy, "Misjudging Hitler", pp. 93–115 from The Origins of the Second World War Reconsidered edited by Gordon Martel, Routledge: London, England, 1999, pp. 98–99.
Kershaw, Ian To Hell and Back: Europe 1914–1949, Ch. 5
Karlsson, Gunnar (2000). History of Iceland. pp. 308–12.
Manikumar, K. A. (2003). A Colonial Economy in the Great Depression, Madras (1929–1937).
Samita
Sen, "Labour, Organization and Gender: The Jute Industry in India in
the 1930s", in Helmut Konrad and Wolfgang Maderthaner, eds. Routes into the Abyss: Coping with Crises in the 1930s (2013) pp. 152–66.
Simmons, Colin (1987). "The Great Depression and Indian Industry: Changing Interpretations and Changing Perceptions". Modern Asian Studies. 21 (3): 585–623. doi:10.1017/S0026749X00009215. JSTOR312643. S2CID145538790.
Frank Barry and Mary F. Daly, "Concurrent Irish Perspectives on the Great Depression" (2010) [ online ]
Frank Barry and Mary E. Daly, "Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression" in Michael Psalidopoulos, The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012), pp. 395–424.
See also B. Girvin, Between Two Worlds: Politics and Economy in Independent Ireland (Dublin: Gill and Macmillan, 1989).
Barry, Frank, and Mary E. Daly. "Irish Perceptions of the Great Depression" (No. iiisdp349. IIIS, 2011.) OnlineArchived 11 August 2015 at the Wayback Machine
Vera Zamagni, The economic history of Italy 1860–1990 (Oxford University Press, 1993)
Fabrizio Mattesini, and Beniamino Quintieri. "Italy and the Great Depression: An analysis of the Italian economy, 1929–1936." Explorations in Economic History (1997) 34#3 pp: 265–294.
Fabrizio
Mattesini and Beniamino Quintieri. "Does a reduction in the length of
the working week reduce unemployment? Some evidence from the Italian
economy during the Great Depression." Explorations in Economic History (2006), 43#3, pp. 413–37.
Myung Soo Cha, "Did Takahashi Korekiyo Rescue Japan from the Great Depression?", The Journal of Economic History 63, No. 1 (March 2003): 127–144.
(For more on the Japanese economy in the 1930s see "MITI and the Japanese Miracle" by Chalmers Johnson.)
Rosemary Thorp, Latin America in the 1930s: the role of the periphery in world crisis (Palgrave Macmillan, 2000).
E. H. Kossmann, The Low Countries: 1780–1940 (1978).
José Cardozo, "The great depression and Portugal" in Michael Psalidopoulos, ed. (2012). The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context Athens: Alpha Bank, ISBN978-960-99793-6-8. pp. 361–394 Online. Archived 13 March 2017 at the Wayback Machine.
Rodriguez, Manuel (2011). A New Deal for the Tropics. Princeton: Markus Wiener. p. 23.
Chiappini, Raphaël; Torre, Dominique; Tosi, Elise (2009). "Romania's unsustainable stabilization: 1929–1933"(PDF). GREDEG Working Papers (2019–43). Groupe de Recherche en Droit, Economie, Gestion: 1–32. Archived(PDF) from the original on 8 July 2021. Retrieved 18 February 2022.
Dan O'Meara, Volkskapitalisme: class, capital, and ideology in the development of Afrikaner nationalism, 1934–1948 (Cambridge University Press, 1983).
Minnaar, Anthony (1994). "Unemployment and relief measures during the Great Depression (1929–1934)". Kleio. 26 (1): 45–85. doi:10.1080/00232084.1994.10823193.
Robert William Davies, Mark Harrison, and Stephen G. Wheatcroft, eds. The economic transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913–1945 (Cambridge University Press, 1994)
Gabriel Tortella and Jordi Palafox, "Banking and Industry in Spain 1918–1936", Journal of European Economic History (1984), 13#2 Special Issue, pp. 81–110.
R. J. Harrison, Economic History of Modern Spain (1978), pp. 129–149.
Göran Therborn, "A Unique Chapter in the History of Democracy: The Swedish Social Democrats", in K. Misgeld et al. (eds), Creating Social Democracy, University Park, Penn State University Press, 1996.
Handley, Paul M. (2006). The King Never Smiles: A Biography of Thailand's Bhumibol Adulyadej. New Haven and London: Yale University Press. p. 37.
Cook, Chris and Bewes, Diccon; What Happened Where: A Guide To Places And Events in Twentieth-Century History p. 115; Routledge, 1997 ISBN1-85728-533-6
Peter Clemens, Prosperity, Depression and the New Deal: The USA 1890–1954, Hodder Education, 4. Auflage, 2008, ISBN978-0-340-96588-7, p. 114.
Charles R. Morris, A Rabble of Dead Money: The Great Crash and the Global Depression: 1929–1939 (PublicAffairs, 2017), 389 pp. online reviewArchived 24 April 2017 at the Wayback Machine
Swanson,
Joseph; Williamson, Samuel (1972). "Estimates of national product and
income for the United States economy, 1919–1941". Explorations in Economic History. 10 (1): 53–73. doi:10.1016/0014-4983(72)90003-4.
Prison Days and Nights, by Victor F. Nelson (New York: Garden City Publishing Co., Inc., 1936)
Robert Goldston, The Great Depression, Fawcett Publications, 1968, p. 228.
Economic Fluctuations,
Maurice W. Lee, Chairman of Economics Dept., Washington State College,
published by R.D. Irwin Inc, Homewood, Illinois, 1955, p. 236.
Business Cycles, James Arthur Estey, Purdue University, Prentice-Hall, 1950, pp. 22–23 chart.
Maurice W. Lee, 1955.
Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. The Coming of the New Deal: 1933–1935. Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003 [1958]. ISBN0-618-34086-6; Schlesinger, Jr., Arthur M. The Politics of Upheaval: 1935–1936. Paperback ed. New York: Houghton Mifflin, 2003 [1960]. ISBN0-618-34087-4
David Taylor, Soul of a People: The WPA Writers' Project Uncovers Depression America (2009).
Jerre Mangione, The Dream and the Deal: The Federal Writers' Project, 1935–1943 (1996)
Jerrold Hirsch, Portrait of America: A Cultural History of the Federal Writers' Project (2006)
Stacy I. Morgan, Rethinking Social Realism: African American art and literature, 1930–1953 (2004), p. 244.
Harry, Lou (1 October 2010). Cincinnati Magazine. Emmis Communications. pp. 59–63. Archived from the original on 15 April 2021. Retrieved 10 July 2017.
William Manchester, The Glory and the Dream: A Narrative History of America, 1932–1972.
Fletcher, T.W. (1961). "The Great Depression of English Agriculture 1873–1896". The Economic History Review. 13 (3). Blackwell Publishing: 417–32. doi:10.2307/2599512. JSTOR2599512.
See "What Can Transition Economies Learn from the First Ten Years? A New World Bank Report," in Transition NewsletterWorldbank.orgArchived 30 May 2012 at archive.today, K-A.kg
Evans-Pritchard, Ambrose (14 September 2010). "IMF Fears 'Social Explosion' From World Jobs Crisis". The Daily Telegraph
(London). "America and Europe face the worst jobs crisis since the
1930s and risk 'an explosion of social unrest' unless they tread
carefully, the International Monetary Fund has warned."
Further reading
Global
Brendon, Piers. The Dark Valley: A Panorama of the 1930s (2000) comprehensive global economic and political history; 816pp
Davis, Joseph S. The World Between the Wars, 1919–39: An Economist's View (1974)
Garraty, John A.The
Great Depression: An Inquiry into the causes, course, and Consequences
of the Worldwide Depression of the Nineteen-Thirties, as Seen by
Contemporaries and in Light of History (1986) online
Garside, W.R. ed. Capitalism in crisis: International responses to the Great Depression (1993), essays by experts
Grossman, Mark. Encyclopedia of the Interwar Years: From 1919 to 1939 (2000). 400 pp. worldwide coverage
Hall Thomas E. and J. David Ferguson. The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies (1998)
Hodson, H.V. Slump and Recovery, 1929–37: A Survey of World Economic Affairs (Oxford UP, 1938). online
Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward C. Prescott. Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century (2007)
League of Nations. World Economic Survey 1935–1936 (1936) online
Rees, Goronwy.The great slump: capitalism in crisis, 1929–33 (1970) online, Marxist.
Rothermund, Dietmar. The Global Impact of the Great Depression (1996)
Woytinsky, Wladimir. The Social Consequences of the Economic Depression (International Labour Office, 1936). Statistics of major economies; not online.
Europe
Aldcroft, Derek H. "Economic Growth in Britain in the Inter-War
Years: A Reassessment." Economic History Review, 20#2, 1967, pp. 311–26.
online
Ambrosius, G. and W. Hibbard, A Social and Economic History of Twentieth-Century Europe (1989)
Broadberry, S. N. The British Economy between the Wars (Basil Blackwell 1986)
Feinstein. Charles H. The European Economy between the Wars (1997)
James, Harold. The German slump : politics and economics, 1924–1936 (1986) online
Kaiser, David E. Economic diplomacy and the origins of the Second World War: Germany, Britain, France and Eastern Europe, 1930–1939 (1980)
Konrad, Helmut and Wolfgang Maderthaner, eds. Routes Into the Abyss: Coping With Crises in the 1930sArchived 24 January 2020 at the Wayback Machine
(Berghahn Books, 2013), 224 pp. Compares political crises in Germany,
Italy, Austria, and Spain with those in Sweden, Japan, China, India,
Turkey, Brazil, and the United States.
Psalidopoulos, Michael, ed. The Great Depression in Europe: Economic Thought and Policy in a National Context (Athens: Alpha Bank, 2012). ISBN978-960-99793-6-8.
Chapters by economic historians cover Finland, Sweden, Belgium,
Austria, Italy, Greece, Turkey, Bulgaria, Yugoslavia, Romania, Spain,
Portugal, and Ireland. table of contentsArchived 13 March 2017 at the Wayback Machine
Young, William H. The Great Depression in America : a cultural encyclopedia (2007) online
Other areas
Brown, Ian. The Economies of Africa and Asia in the Inter-war Depression (1989)
Drinot, Paulo, and Alan Knight, eds. The Great Depression in Latin America (2014) excerpt
Latham, Anthony, and John Heaton, The Depression and the Developing World, 1914–1939 (1981).
Shiroyama, Tomoko. China during the Great Depression : market, state, and the world economy, 1929–1937 (2008) online
Focus on economic theory or econometrics
Bernanke, Ben. "The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach" Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking (1995) 27#1 pp 1–28 online
Eichengreen, Barry J. Hall of mirrors : the Great Depression, the great recession, and the uses-and misuses-of history (2015), leading economist compares economic decline after 1929 and after 2008. online
Eichengreen, Barry. Golden Fetters: The gold standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. 1992.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Marc Flandreau. The Gold Standard in Theory and History (1997)
Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960 (1963), monetarist interpretation (heavily statistical)
Glasner, David, ed. Business Cycles and Depressions (Routledge, 1997), 800 pp. Excerpt
Haberler, Gottfried.The World Economy, money, and the great depression 1919–1939 (1976)
Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward C. Prescott, eds. Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century (2007), essays by economists on the U.S., Britain, France, Germany, Italy and on tariffs; statistical
Kindleberger, Charles P. The World in Depression, 1929–1939 (3rd ed. 2013) online
Madsen, Jakob B. "Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression", Southern Economic Journal, (2001) 67#4 pp. 848–68 online at JSTOR.
Markwell, Donald. John Maynard Keynes and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace (Oxford University Press, 2006).
Mundell, R.A. "A Reconsideration of the Twentieth Century", American Economic Review 90#3 (2000), pp. 327–40 online version
Richardson, H. W. "The Basis of Economic Recovery in the Nineteen-Thirties: A Review and a New Interpretation." Economic History Review, 15#2 (1962), pp. 344–63. online; focus on United Kingdom.
Romer, Christina D. "The Nation in Depression", Journal of Economic Perspectives (1993) 7#2 pp. 19–39 in JSTORArchived 3 July 2016 at the Wayback Machine, statistical comparison of U.S. and other countries